WELCOME |
![]() |
![]() comments, ephemera, speculation, etc. (protected political speech and personal opinion) 2022- 2022-05-06 a BLACK & WHITE I This analysis does not
consider the substantial costs to industry resulting
from reduced productivity due to hiring unqualified workers of color. AFFIRMATIVE ACTION: THE ROBIN
HOOD EFFECT
In this essay La Griffe du Lion models the effect of affirmative action on the income of whites, blacks and Hispanics. It is shown that on average a black worker between the ages of 25 and 64 earns an extra $9,400 a year because of affirmative action. Hispanics also benefit to the tune of almost $4,000 a year. However, being a zero-sum game, white workers pay an average of about $1,900 annually to foot the bill. Decades have elapsed since the major civil rights laws were passed, yet we still find some minority groups lagging behind. Often achieving well politically, blacks in particular remain far down the economic ladder. Centuries of slavery followed by persistent discrimination and white racism are the usual suspects. More exotic explanations include lowered expectations, reluctance to act white, etc. But since none of this affects g-loaded test scores where the black-white difference has remained remarkably constant, some principle of parsimony should direct us elsewhere for answers. Parsimony, however, is not in the legislator's lexicon; nor is it part of the system of rationalizations we call justice. So we are left with implausible speculations to justify the system of race and sex-based preferences we call affirmative action. Affirmative action is not free. No matter how large or small a business is, it is vulnerable to complaints of discrimination by applicants, employees and former employees. In the interest of the bottom line, employers invariably capitulate. The consequences of not conforming are more costly. Brimelow and Spencer in When Quotas Replace Merit, Everybody Suffers, Forbes, February 15, 1993, assert that the greatest cost of affirmative action results from not being able to choose the best economic alternatives. They estimate this cost alone at $236 billion for 1991. Administrative costs associated with affirmative action add another $100 billion or so per year. Most other estimates also put the annual bill for affirmative action in the two to four hundred-billion dollar ballpark. The Robin Hood Effect There is another cost of affirmative action, the most insidious and cruel of all. Different from the others, we cannot measure it as reduced GDP. It is a tax on one group to reward another. The concept is not abstract. It is well-known to people in the workplace when they see less qualified minorities steal away their opportunities. Resentment is often palpable, and the cost is psychological as well as economic. We address the economic component here. Whenever someone gets preferential access to a job or a promotion because of his race or ethnicity, someone else of a different race or ethnicity gets displaced. In the U.S., the displaced person is usually a non-Hispanic white. The result is an income transfer from whites to "preferred" minorities. We call it the Robin Hood effect. We have assessed its size by using a simple device: the correlation of income and IQ. From this relation we can construct a profile of the workforce as it would exist in a meritocracy, The Income-IQ
Nexus
Then there is luck. A person must be available when an opportunity pops up. Geography may be a factor. New Yorkers have more opportunity to earn well than West Virginians. Sometimes, ties to family and geography will constrain people from seeking or taking the best jobs. Lastly, other qualities like personality, work habits, ethical or moral values, to name a few, factor into the ability to earn. All these and more produce fluctuations in the income-IQ curve, a problem we need to solve. By
dividing the workforce into broad ranges, say
quintiles,
we can virtually eliminate the fluctuations. Each
quintile will contain
millions of earners. Dentists and professors, with
rather different incomes,
will fall into the same income quintile. If IQ
correlates well with income,
it will correlate almost perfectly with the income
of a work force so partitioned. 1) What would income distribution by race and ethnicity look like in Utopia?Utopian distribution. In Utopia, races and ethnic groups are indistinguishable from one another except for obvious physical characteristics. Utopia is the prevailing construct in the West. It is the premise upon which affirmative action is built. In Utopia, each quintile will be populated in proportion to the racial-ethnic composition of the workforce at large. Each quintile will be racially and ethnically indistinguishable from any other (figure 1). The Utopian justification of affirmative action is illustrated by the testimony of Representative Sheila Jackson Lee before the Subcommittee on the Constitution, Committee on the Judiciary, U.S. House of Representatives, December 7, 1995. Speaking of women, roughly 50 percent of the population, she argued:
Meritocratic
distribution. To generate the rank ordering of the workforce on IQ, required to construct the meritocratic distribution, we used mean IQ differences from the National Longitudinal Study of Youth (NLSY): 1.21 SD for the white-black difference, and 0.93 SD for the white-Hispanic difference. The mathematical procedure for populating the quintiles is described in an Appendix. Actual
distribution. The ADS classifies workers as black, white, Hispanic, and white-not-Hispanic. Since Hispanics can be of any race, we formed the classification Hispanic-white by subtracting the white-not-Hispanic data from the white data. Ultimately, we formed three non-overlapping groups: black, Hispanic-white, and non-Hispanic white. For simplicity, from now on we refer to these groups as black, Hispanic and white, respectively. All but a few percent of Americans who earned income in 1997 were included in our analysis. (The ADS data of 1997 did not include Asian Americans.) Income in the ADS is broken into $2,500 bins: $0 to $2,499, $2,500 to $4,999, and so on through $97,500 to $99,999. Finally, the last bin is for earners making $100,000 or more. The ADS breaks down the population of each bin by race, ethnicity, sex and age. We included in our sample only workers between the ages of 25 and 64, the mainstream of full-timers. They numbered 126,362,000 in 1997. Starting at the low-income end, we added earners in adjacent bins until we got as close as possible to 20 percent of the workforce. In this way we partitioned the workforce into near-quintiles, each containing 20±1 percent of all workers. By using near-quintiles instead of true quintiles, we sacrificed nothing but symmetry. Near-quintiles flatten the fluctuations as well as true quintiles. Table 1 summarizes the partition.[...] The size of the Robin Hood effect. The income lost to whites is easily assessed. The number of whites displaced into or out of a given quintile is the difference between the white quintile population in a meritocracy and that actually observed. The number of displaced whites times the midpoint income of a quintile approximates the lost income for that quintile. The total income lost is the sum of losses over the 5 quintiles. In 1997, because of affirmative action, about $192 billion in income was transferred from whites to preferred minorities. If we perform precisely the same calculation for blacks and Hispanics, we can break down the $192 billion into the amounts gained by each group. We find that $144.3 billion was transferred to blacks and $47.5 billion to Hispanics. Dividing these gains by the respective numbers of black and Hispanic workers, we can compute their average annual income enhancement. In 1997, on average a black was subsidized to the tune of about $9,400; a Hispanic gained an average of about $3,900. The cost of these subsidies was spread over 98,782,000 white workers who suffered an average loss of about $1,900 to pay the bill. The cascade effect. The net displacement of whites by minorities is not uniformly spread across the quintiles. When high-earning whites are displaced down the employment ladder, they displace other whites downward by exerting pressure on the rung below. The effect is like a cascade. At the bottom there is no rung left. Low IQ whites, who in an affirmative action-free marketplace would be competitive in the $10,000 to $20,000 bracket, now pile up in the lowest-income quintile. Although affirmative action affects every white, the largest number affected are the least intelligent and competitive. Figure 4 illustrates the cascade effect. Summary Decades of affirmative action have brought enormous changes to the American workforce. Blacks and Hispanics have gained generously, but at the expense of whites. The costs of these gains have been borne by the majority white population. To some extent the costs are masked by the relative sizes of the white and minority groups. Large numbers of whites foot the bill for relatively few minority workers. Thus, individual minority workers can achieve large earning enhancements, with the cost to whites spread over a large population. A philosophical case could be made for affirmative action in this way. Such an argument, however, is unlikely to surface while the Utopian mindset prevails. In the current political climate, we have nothing to look forward to but an asymptotic approach to Utopia. (read more) See also: THE COLOR OF MERITOCRACY See also: THE DEATH OF MERITOCRACY ______________________ Permission is hereby granted to any and all to copy and paste any entry on this page and convey it electronically along with its URL, ______________________ |
...
News and facts for
those sick and tired of the National Propaganda Radio
version of reality.
|
|||||
|
If
you let them redefine words, they will control
language. If you let them control language, they will control thoughts. If you let them control thoughts, they will control you. They will own you. |
© 2020 - 2021 - thenotimes.com - All Rights Reserved |